Fundamentals of Microeconomics: Introduction

HOME | Project Management

Data Warehousing / Mining

Software Testing | Technical Writing



An Economist's Theory of Reincarnation: If you're good, you come back on a higher level. Cats come back as dogs, dogs come back as horses, and people--if they've been really good like George Washington--come back as money.

Introduction

If each of us could get all the food, clothing, and toys we wanted without working, no one would study economics. Unfortunately, most of the good things in life are scarce--we can't all have as much as we want. Thus, scarcity is the mother of economics.

Microeconomics is the study of how individuals and firms make themselves as well off as possible in a world of scarcity and the consequences of those individual decisions for markets and the entire economy. In studying microeconomics, we examine how individual consumers and firms make decisions and how the interaction of many individual decisions affects markets and the entire economy.

Microeconomics is often called price theory to emphasize the important role that prices play. Microeconomics explains how the actions of all buyers and sellers deter mine prices and how prices influence the decisions and actions of individual buyers and sellers.

===========

microeconomics--the study of how individuals and firms make themselves as well off as possible in a world of scarcity and the consequences of those individual decisions for markets and the entire economy

=========

In this section, we examine three main topics

1. Microeconomics: The Allocation of Scarce Resources. Microeconomics is the study of the allocation of scarce resources.

2. Models. Economists use models to make testable predictions.

3. Uses of Microeconomic Models. Individuals, governments, and firms use microeconomic models and predictions in decision making.

===============

1. Microeconomics: The Allocation of Scarce Resources

Individuals and firms allocate their limited resources to make themselves as well off as possible. Consumers pick the mix of goods and services that makes them as happy as possible given their limited wealth. Firms decide which goods to produce, where to produce them, how much to produce to maximize their profits, and how to produce those levels of output at the lowest cost by using more or less of various inputs such as labor, capital, materials, and energy. The owners of a depletable natural resource such as oil decide when to use it. Government decision makers-to benefit consumers, firms, or government bureaucrats-decide which goods and ser vices the government produces and whether to subsidize, tax, or regulate industries and consumers.

Trade-Offs

People make trade-offs because they can't have everything. A society faces three key trade-offs:

¦ Which goods and services to produce: If a society produces more cars, it must produce fewer of other goods and services, because there are only so many resources-workers, raw materials, capital, and energy-available to produce goods.

¦ How to produce: To produce a given level of output, a firm must use more of one input if it uses less of another input. For example, cracker and cookie manufacturers switch between palm oil and coconut oil, depending on which is less expensive.

¦ Who gets the goods and services: The more of society's goods and services you get, the less someone else gets.

Who Makes the Decisions

These three allocation decisions may be made explicitly by the government or may reflect the interaction of independent decisions by many individual consumers and firms. In the former Soviet Union, the government told manufacturers how many cars of each type to make and which inputs to use to make them. The government also decided which consumers would get a car.

In most other countries, how many cars of each type are produced and who gets them are determined by how much it costs to make cars of a particular quality in the least expensive way and how much consumers are willing to pay for them.

More consumers would own a handmade Rolls-Royce and fewer would buy a mass-produced Ford Taurus if a Rolls were not 13 times more expensive than a Taurus.

market--an exchange mechanism that allows buyers to trade with sellers.

Prices Determine Allocations

Prices link the decisions about which goods and services to produce, how to produce them, and who gets them. Prices influence the decisions of individual consumers and firms, and the interactions of these decisions by consumers, firms, and the government determine price.

Interactions between consumers and firms take place in a market, which is an exchange mechanism that allows buyers to trade with sellers. A market may be a town square where people go to trade food and clothing, or it may be an international telecommunications network over which people buy and sell financial securities. Typically, when we talk about a single market, we refer to trade in a single good or group of goods that are closely related, such as soft drinks, movies, novels, or automobiles.

Most of this guide concerns how prices are determined within a market. We show that the number of buyers and sellers in a market and the amount of information they have help determine whether the price equals the cost of production. We also show that if there is no market-and hence no market price-serious problems, such as high levels of pollution, result.

2. Models

Everything should be made as simple as possible, but not simpler.

-Albert Einstein

To explain how individuals and firms allocate resources and how market prices are determined, economists use a model: a description of the relationship between two or more economic variables. Economists also use models to predict how a change in one variable will affect another.

model -- a description of the relationship between two or more economic variables

===========

Application

Income Threshold Model and China

According to an income threshold model, no one who has an income level below a particular threshold buys a particular consumer durable, such as a refrigerator or car.

The theory also holds that almost everyone whose income is above that threshold buys the product.

If this theory is correct, we predict that, as most people's incomes rise above the threshold in emergent economies, consumer durable purchases will increase from near zero to large numbers virtually overnight. This prediction is consistent with evidence from Malaysia, where the income threshold for buying a car is about $4,000.

In China, incomes have risen rapidly and now exceed the threshold levels for many types of durable goods. As a result, many experts correctly predicted that the greatest consumer durable goods sales boom in history would take place there. Anticipating this boom, many companies have greatly increased their investments in durable goods manufacturing plants in China. Annual foreign direct investments have gone from $916 million a year in 1983 to $116 billion in 2011. In expectation of this growth potential, even traditional political opponents of the People's Republic-Taiwan, South Korea, and Russia-are investing in China.

One of the most desirable durable goods is a car. Li Rifu, a 46-year-old Chinese farmer and watch repairman, thought that buying a car would improve the odds that his 22- and 24-year-old sons would find girlfriends, marry, and produce grandchildren. Soon after Mr. Li purchased his Geely King Kong for the equivalent of $9,000, both sons met girlfriends, and his older son got married. Four-fifths of all new cars sold in China are bought by first-time customers. An influx of first-time buyers was responsible for China's nine-fold increase in car sales from 2000 to 2009. By 2010, China became the second largest producer of automobiles in the world, trailing only Germany. In addition, foreign automobile companies built Chinese plants. For example, Ford invested $600 million in its Chongqing factory in 2012.

===========

Simplifications by Assumption

We stated the income threshold model in words, but we could have presented it using graphs or mathematics. Regardless of how the model is described, an economic model is a simplification of reality that contains only its most important features.

Without simplifications, it is difficult to make predictions because the real world is too complex to analyze fully.

By analogy, if the manual accompanying your new TiVo recorder has a diagram showing the relationships between all the parts in the TiVo, the diagram will be overwhelming and useless. In contrast, if it shows a photo of the lights on the front of the machine with labels describing the significance of each light, the manual is useful and informative.

Economists make many assumptions to simplify their models.

[2. When using the income threshold model to explain car purchasing behavior in China, we assume that factors other than income, such as the color of cars, are irrelevant to the decision to buy cars. Therefore, we ignore the color of cars that are sold in China in describing the relationship between average income and the number of cars consumers want. If this assumption is correct, by ignoring color, we make our analysis of the auto market simpler without losing important details. If we're wrong and these ignored issues are important, our predictions may be inaccurate. ]

Throughout this guide, we start with strong assumptions to simplify our models.

Later, we add complexities. For example, in most of the guide, we assume that consumers know the price each firm charges. In many markets, such as the New York Stock Exchange, this assumption is realistic. It is not realistic in other markets, such as the market for used automobiles, in which consumers do not know the prices each firm charges. To devise an accurate model for markets in which consumers have limited information, we add consumer uncertainty about price into the model in Section 19.

Testing Theories

Blore's Razor: When given a choice between two theories, take the one that is funnier.

Economic theory is the development and use of a model to test hypotheses, which are predictions about cause and effect. We are interested in models that make clear, testable predictions, such as "If the price rises, the quantity demanded falls." A theory that said "People's behavior depends on their tastes, and their tastes change randomly at random intervals" is not very useful because it does not lead to testable predictions.

Economists test theories by checking whether predictions are correct. If a prediction does not come true, they may reject the theory.

[3. Economists use a model until it is refuted by evidence or until a better model is developed. ]

A good model makes sharp, clear predictions that are consistent with reality.

Some very simple models make sharp predictions that are incorrect, and other more complex models make ambiguous predictions-any outcome is possible-which are untestable. The skill in model building is to chart a middle ground.

The purpose of this guide is to teach you how to think like an economist in the sense that you can build testable theories using economic models or apply existing models to new situations. Although economists think alike in that they develop and use test able models, they often disagree. One may present a logically consistent argument that prices will go up next quarter. Another, using a different but equally logical theory, may contend that prices will fall. If the economists are reasonable, they agree that pure logic alone cannot resolve their dispute. Indeed, they agree that they'll have to use empirical evidence-facts about the real world-to find out which prediction is correct.

[2. An economist, an engineer, and a physicist are stranded on a desert island with a can of beans but no can opener. How should they open the can? The engineer proposes hitting the can with a rock. The physicist suggests building a fire under it to build up pressure and burst the can open. The economist thinks for a while and then says, "Assume that we have a can opener. . . ." ]

[3. We can use evidence on whether a theory's predictions are correct to refute the theory but not to prove it. If a model's prediction is inconsistent with what actually happened, the model must be wrong, so we reject it. Even if the model's prediction is consistent with reality, however, the model's prediction may be correct for the wrong reason. Hence we cannot prove that the model is correct-we can only fail to reject it. ]

Although one economist's model may differ from another's, a key assumption in most microeconomic models is that individuals allocate their scarce resources so as to make themselves as well off as possible. Of all affordable combinations of goods, consumers pick the bundle of goods that gives them the most possible enjoyment.

Firms try to maximize their profits given limited resources and existing technology. That resources are limited plays a crucial role in these models. Were it not for scarcity, people could consume unlimited amounts of goods and services, and sellers could become rich beyond limit.

As we show throughout this guide, the maximizing behavior of individuals and firms determines society's three main allocation decisions: which goods are produced, how they are produced, and who gets them. For example, diamond-studded pocket combs will be sold only if firms find it profitable to sell them. The firms will make and sell these combs only if consumers value the combs at least as much as it costs the firm to produce them. Consumers will buy the combs only if they get more pleasure from the combs than they would from the other goods they could buy with the same resources.

Positive Versus Normative

The use of models of maximizing behavior sometimes leads to predictions that seem harsh or heartless. For instance, a World Bank economist predicted that if an African government used price controls to keep the price of food low during a drought, food shortages would occur and people would starve. The predicted outcome is awful, but the economist was not heartless. The economist was only making a scientific prediction about the relationship between cause and effect: Price controls (cause) lead to food shortages and starvation (effect).

Such a scientific prediction is known as a positive statement: a testable hypothesis about cause and effect. "Positive" does not mean that we are certain about the truth of our statement-it only indicates that we can test the truth of the statement.

If the World Bank economist is correct, should the government control prices? If the government believes the economist's predictions, it knows that the low prices help those consumers who are lucky enough to be able to buy as much food as they want while hurting both the firms that sell food and the people who are unable to buy as much food as they want, some of whom may die. As a result, the government's decision whether to use price controls turns on whether the government cares more about the winners or the losers. In other words, to decide on its policy, the government makes a value judgment.

Instead of first making a prediction and testing it before making a value judgment to decide whether to use price controls, the government could make a value judgment directly. The value judgment could be based on the belief that "because people should have prepared for the drought, the government should not try to help them by keeping food prices low." Alternatively, the judgment could be based on the view that "people should be protected against price gouging during a drought, so the government should use price controls." These two statements are not scientific predictions. Each is a value judgment or normative statement: a conclusion as to whether something is good or bad. A normative statement cannot be tested because a value judgment cannot be refuted by evidence. It is a prescription rather than a prediction. A normative statement concerns what somebody believes should happen; a positive statement concerns what will happen.

Although a normative conclusion can be drawn without first conducting a positive analysis, a policy debate will be more informed if positive analyses are conducted first.

[4. For instance, if your normative belief is that the government should help the poor, should you vote for a candidate who advocates a higher minimum wage (a law that requires that firms pay wages at or above a specified level)? One who believes in a European-style welfare system (guaranteeing health care, housing, and other basic goods and services)? A politician who wants an end to our current welfare system? Someone who wants to implement a negative income tax (in which the less income a person has, the more the government gives that person)? Or a candidate who favors job training programs? Positive economic analysis can be used to predict whether these programs will benefit poor people but not whether they are good or bad. Using these predictions and your value judgment, you can decide for whom to vote. ]

Economists' emphasis on positive analysis has implications for what we study and even our use of language. For example, many economists stress that they study people's wants rather than their needs. Although people need certain minimum levels of food, shelter, and clothing to survive, most people in developed economies have enough money to buy goods well in excess of the minimum levels necessary to maintain life. Consequently, in wealthy countries, calling something a "need" is often a value judgment. You almost certainly have been told by some elder that "you need a college education." That person was probably making a value judgment--"you should go to college"--rather than a scientific prediction that you will suffer terrible economic deprivation if you do not go to college. We can't test such value judgments, but we can test a hypothesis such as "One-third of the college-age population wants to go to college at current prices."

3. Uses of Microeconomic Models

Because microeconomic models explain why economic decisions are made and allow us to make predictions, they can be very useful for individuals, governments, and firms in making decisions. Throughout this guide, we consider examples of how microeconomics aids in actual decision making.

Individuals can use microeconomics to make purchasing and other decisions (Sections 4 and 5). Consumers' purchasing and investing decisions are affected by inflation and cost of living adjustments (Section 5). Whether it pays financially to go to college depends, in part, on interest rates (Section 16). Consumers decide for whom to vote based on candidates' views on economic issues.

Firms must decide which production methods to use to minimize cost (Section 7)

and maximize profit (starting with Section 8). They may choose a complex pricing scheme or advertise to raise profits (Section 12). They select strategies to maximize profit when competing with a small number of other firms (Sections 13 and 14). Some firms reduce consumer information to raise profits (Section 19). Firms use economic principles to structure contracts with other firms (Section 20).

Your government's elected and appointed officials use (or could use) economic models in many ways. Recent administrations have placed increased emphasis on economic analysis. Today, economic and environmental impact studies are required before many projects can commence. The President's Council of Economic Advisers and other federal economists analyze and advise national government agencies on the likely economic effects of all major policies.

4. Some economists draw the normative conclusion that, as social scientists, economists should restrict ourselves to positive analyses. Others argue that we shouldn't give up our right to make value judgments just like the next person (who happens to be biased, prejudiced, and pigheaded, unlike us).

One major use of microeconomic models by governments is to predict the probable impact of a policy before it is adopted. For example, economists predict the likely impact of a tax on the prices consumers pay and on the tax revenues raised (Section 3), whether a price control will create a shortage (Section 2), the differential effects of tariffs and quotas on trade (Section 9), and the effects of regulation on monopoly price and the quantity sold (Section 11).

Summary

1. Microeconomics: The Allocation of Scarce Resources. Microeconomics is the study of the allocation of scarce resources. Consumers, firms, and governments must make allocation decisions. The three key trade-offs a society faces are which goods and ser vices to produce, how to produce them, and who gets them. These decisions are interrelated and depend on the prices that consumers and firms face and on government actions. Market prices affect the decisions of individual consumers and firms, and the interaction of the decisions of individual consumers and firms deter mines market prices. The organization of the market, especially the number of firms in the market and the information consumers and firms have, plays an important role in determining whether the market price is equal to or higher than marginal cost.

2. Models. Models based on economic theories are used to predict the future or to answer questions about how some change, such as a tax increase, affects various sectors of the economy. A good theory is simple to use and makes clear, testable predictions that are not refuted by evidence. Most microeconomic models are based on maximizing behavior.

Economists use models to construct positive hypotheses concerning how a cause leads to an effect. These positive questions can be tested. In contrast, normative statements, which are value judgments, cannot be tested.

3. Uses of Microeconomic Models. Individuals, governments, and firms use microeconomic models and pre dictions to make decisions. For example, to maximize its profits, a firm needs to know consumers' decision making criteria, the trade-offs between various ways of producing and marketing its product, government regulations, and other factors. For large companies, beliefs about how a firm's rivals will react to its actions play a critical role in how it forms its business strategies.

| NEXT

top of page  Similar Articles  Home